Continuity:
A small change in a bundle can only cause small changes to the preference rankings and level.
Put differently, if A is preferred to B, then situations suitably close to A must also be preferred to B.
Main idea: instead of preference relations, we can describe a consumers' preferences using utility functions.
Intuition: A utility function assigns a "satisfaction level" (a number) to each alternative or bundle.
Instead of saying: $ iPhone7 \succ Galaxy8 $, we say $ U(iPhone7) > U(Galaxy8) $
Instead of saying: $ (2 \textrm{ Beers}, 3 \textrm{ Pizzas} ) \succ (1 \textrm{ Beers}, 4 \textrm{ Pizzas} ) $, we say $ U(2, 3) > U(1, 4) $
But, how does a preference relations and a utility function connect?
Then, these preferences can be represented by a (continuous) utility function.
Note on reflexivity, monotonicity, convexity.
When do we say that we a utility function represents someone's preference relations?
A utility function $ U(x) $ represents a preference relation $ \succsim $ when:
$ x’ \succ x’’ \iff U(x’) > U(x’’), ~~ $ for any $ x' $ and $ x'' $
$ x’ \succsim x’’ \iff U(x’) \geq U(x’’) ~~ $, for any $ x' $ and $ x'' $
$ x’ \sim x’’ \iff U(x’) = U(x’), ~~ $ for any $ x' $ and $ x'' $
Intuitively, $ U() $ represents a preference relation if it yields the same ranking of alternatives.
That is, like preference relations, utility is an ordinal (i.e. ordering) concept.
If, for example, $ U(x) = 6 $ and $ U(y) = 2 $ then bundle $ x $ is strictly preferred to bundle $ y $. But we cannot say: " $ x $ is preferred three times as much as is $ y $ ".
An indifference curve contains equally preferred bundles.
In terms of utility, all bundles in an indifference curve give the same utility level:
In other words, indifference curves are the level curves of utility functions.
$ u(x_1, x_2) = x_1 ~ x_2 $
The preferences of a certain consumer can be described/represented by more than one utility function.
That is, there is no unique utility function for a preference relation.
Two utility functions $ U() $ and $ V() $ represent the same preferences, if we can obtain $ V() $ by applying a strictly increasing function on U():
That is, if we can write $ V = f( U() ) $ where $ f() $ is strictly increasing.
[ ask students about strictly increasing functions ]
Suppose $ U(x_1,x_2) = x_1 x_2 $ represents some preferences.
You have bundles $ (4,1), (2,3) $ and $ (2,2) $.
Under this utility function: $ U(2,3) = 6 > U(4,1) = U(2,2) = 4 $;
Therefore, we know that: $ (2,3) \succ (4,1) \sim (2,2) $.
Suppose we define $ V = U^2 $.
Then, $ V(x_1,x_2) = (x_1 x_2)^2 = x_1^2 x_2^2 \quad $
...and so, $ V(2,3) = 36 > V(4,1) = V(2,2) = 16 $
SO! again $ (2,3) \succ (4,1) \sim (2,2) $.
That is, $ V() $ preserves the same order as $ U() $ and therefore represents the same preferences.
Suppose we define $ W = 2U + 10 $.
Then, $ W(x_1,x_2) = 2 (x_1 x_2) + 10 $
...and so, $ W(2,3) = 22 > W(4,1) = W(2,2) = 18 $
SO! again! $ (2,3) \succ (4,1) \sim (2,2) $.
That is, $ W() $ preserves the same order as $ U() $ and therefore represents the same preferences.
A good is a commodity unit which increases utility (gives a more preferred bundle).
A bad is a commodity unit which decreases utility (gives a less preferred bundle).
A neutral is a commodity unit which does not change utility (gives an equally preferred bundle).
For home: Draw indifference curves for each of them
Identify the utility function: $ U(x_1, x_2) $.
Set the utility level to a constant level $ k $: $ U(x_1, x_2) = k $.
Solve for $ x_2 $ in the previous equation to obtain a generic indifference curve.
Give $ k $ an arbitrary value and draw the curve.
To draw another curve, set $ k $ equal to another value and draw again.
Utility: $ U(x_1, x_2) = x_1^{0.5} x_2 $
Utility at a constant level: $ x_1^{0.5} x_2 = k $
Solve for x2: $ x_2 = \frac{k}{x_1^{0.5}} $.
Give $ k $ a value: $ x_2 = \frac{ 10 }{x_1^{0.5}} $. Draw!
Give $ k $ another value: $ x_2 = \frac{ 20 }{x_1^{0.5}} $. Draw!
General: $ ~ U(x_1,x_2) = \alpha x_1 + \beta x_2 ~~ $, for $ \alpha, \beta > 0 $
Example: $ ~ U(x_1,x_2) = x_1 + x_2 $
General: $ ~ U(x_1,x_2) = \textrm{min} \{ \frac{x_1}{\alpha}, \frac{x_2}{\beta} \} ~~ $, for $ \alpha, \beta > 0 $.
Example: $ ~ U = \textrm{min} \{ x_1, x_2 \} ~~ $
General $ U(x_1,x_2) = x_1^a x_2^b $ with a > 0 and b > 0
Examples:
$ U(x_1,x_2) = x_1^{0.5} x_2^{0.5} \quad $ (that is, $ a = b = 1/2 $)
$ U(x_1,x_2) = x_1 x_2^3 \quad $ (that is, $ a = 1, b = 3 $)
$ U(x_1,x_2) = x_1^{2} x_2^{0.75} \quad $ (that is, $ a = 2, b = 0.75 $)
Marginal means “incremental”.
The marginal utility of commodity $ x_1 $ is the rate-of-change of total utility as the quantity of commodity $ x_1 $ consumed increases.
$ MU_{x_1} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_1} $ and $ MU_{x_2} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_2} $
To know whether $ MU_{x_1} $ is increasing or decreasing in $ x_1 $, we take the derivative of $ MU_{x_1} $ with respect to $ x_1 $. That is, we calculate: $ \frac{\partial MU_{x_1}}{\partial x_1} $
Utility: $ U(x_1,x_2) = x_1^{0.5} x_2^2 $
Marginal Utilities:
$ MU_{x_1} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_1} = 0.5 x_1^{-0.5} x_2^2 $
$ MU_{x_2} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_2} = 2 x_1^{0.5} x_2^1 $
Utility: $ U(x_1,x_2) = a x_1 + b x_2 $
Marginal Utilities:
$ MU_{x_1} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_1} = a $
$ MU_{x_2} = \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_2} = b $
Utility: $ U(x_1,x_2) = min \{ x_1 , x_2 \} $
Claim: $ MRS \equiv \frac{d x_2}{d x_1} = - \frac{ MU_{x_1} }{ MU_{x_2} } $
Here is the math:
Remember, the equation for an indifference curve is: $ U(x_1,x_2) = k $, where satisfaction, $ k $, is a constant.
Do total differentiation: $ \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_1} d x_1 +
\frac{\partial U}{\partial x_2} d x_2 = d k $,
But $ dk = 0 $ since $ k $ is a constant, and $ \frac{\partial U}{\partial x_i} $ can be replaced by $ MU_{x_i} $. That is: $ MU_{x_1} d x_1 + MU_{x_2} d x_2 = 0 $
We solve for $ \frac{d x_2}{d x_1} $ and we get: $ \frac{d x_2}{d x_1} = - \frac{ MU_{x_1} }{ MU_{x_2} } $